Demand: marginal social benefit (MSB)
Supply: marginal social cost (MSC)
Equilibrium: MSB=MSC
Principle of “payment in accordance with product”
Price system (when markets work well) properly aligns incentives on the margin
Changes that affect others are mitigated through price system
Called pecuniary externalities
The real problem is that it is external to the price system!
People base decisions off of their preferences and opportunity costs of resources for society (captured in prices)
Prices properly negotiate the opportunity costs and provide information to people
But without price, decisions do not internalize those effects!
A.C. Pigou
1877-1959
1920, The Economics of Welfare
Defines (real) externality as divergence between private and social cost/benefit on the margin
People should pay average externality of their actions
Problem with externality is that there is a missing price!
Marginal Private Cost to producer is less than Marginal Social Cost to society
Market Equilibrium (B) too much q at too low p compared to Social Optimum (A)
Marginal Private Cost to producer is less than Marginal Social Cost to society
Market Equilibrium (B) too much q at too low p compared to Social Optimum (A)
Marginal Private Cost to producer is less than Marginal Social Cost to society
Market Equilibrium (B) too much q at too low p compared to Social Optimum (A)
Overproduction due to external cost
A deadweight loss from overproduction
A.C. Pigou
1877-1959
Set a specific tax t=MSC−MPC
Eliminates the DWL
Internalizes the externality into the price system
Producers (and consumers) now consider the true cost to society
"Sitting is banned in the following places: "in St. Mark’s Square and in Piazzetta dei Leoncini, beneath the arcades and on the steps of the Procuratie Nuove, the Napoleonic Wing, the Sansovino Library, beneath the arcades of the Ducal Palace, in the impressive entranceway to St. Mark’s Square otherwise known as Piazzetta San Marco and its jetty." ($200)
"I. A carbon tax offers the most cost-effective lever to reduce carbon emissions at the scale and speed that is necessary. By correcting a well-known market failure, a carbon tax will send a powerful price signal that harnesses the invisible hand of the marketplace to steer economic actors towards a low-carbon future."
Signed by 27 Economics Nobel Laureates, 4 former Federal Reserve chairs, among many other famous economists
"II. A carbon tax should increase every year until emissions reductions goals are met and be revenue neutral to avoid debates over the size of government. A consistently rising carbon price will encourage technological innovation and large-scale infrastructure development. It will also accelerate the diffusion of carbon-efficient goods and services."
Signed by 27 Economics Nobel Laureates, 4 former Federal Reserve chairs, among many other famous economists
"III. A sufficiently robust and gradually rising carbon tax will replace the need for various carbon regulations that are less efficient. Substituting a price signal for cumbersome regulations will promote economic growth and provide the regulatory certainty companies need for long-term investment in clean-energy alternatives."
Signed by 27 Economics Nobel Laureates, 4 former Federal Reserve chairs, among many other famous economists
In 1802, Lodowick Post organized a fox hunt in Southampton, NY
Jesse Pierson appears “out of nowhere,” kills, and claims the fox for his own
Post sued Pierson to get the fox back
Legal question: When do you own an animal?
NY Supreme Court ruled for Pierson (who killed fox)
“If the first seeing, starting, or pursuing such animals...should afford the basis of actions against others for intercepting and killing them, it would prove a fertile source of quarrels and litigation”
“However uncourteous or unkind the conduct of Pierson towards Post, in this instance, may have been, yet his act was productive of no injury or damage for which a legal remedy can be applied. We are of opinion the judgment below was erroneous, and ought to be reversed.”
“[A] fox is a "wild and noxious beast." Both parties have regarded him, as the law of nations does a pirate, "hostem humani generis,"...His depredations on farmers and on barn yards, have not been forgotten; and to put him to death wherever found, is allowed to be meritorious, and of public benefit. Hence it follows, that our decision should have in view the greatest possible encouragement to the destruction of an animal, so cunning and ruthless in his career.”
“But who would keep a pack of hounds; or what gentleman, at the sound of the horn, and at peep of day, would mount his steed, and for hours together...pursue the windings of this wily quadruped, if, just as night came on, and his stratagems and strength were nearly exhausted, a saucy intruder, who had not shared in the honours or labours of the chase, were permitted to come in at the death, and bear away in triumph the object of pursuit?”
If Pierson gets the fox
If Post gets the fox
Tradeoff between simplicity and good incentives
My neighbor likes tall trees
You want to have a party
I own a small plant located on a river
Example: There is a car which you value at $3,000, and I value at $4,000.
Example: There is a car which you value at $3,000, and I value at $4,000.
It is efficient for me to end up with the car.
Suppose I start out with the car
Example: There is a car which you value at $3,000, and I value at $4,000.
It is efficient for me to end up with the car.
Suppose I start out with the car
Suppose instead, you own the car
Example: There is a car which you value at $3,000, and I value at $4,000.
It is efficient for me to end up with the car.
Suppose I start out with the car
Suppose instead, you own the car
It does not matter who is initially assigned a property right, our bargaining will reach the efficient result!
If transaction costs are low, with well-defined and tradeable property rights, parties can bargain voluntarily to reach the efficient outcome.
Coase: there is nothing new or radical here, if you understand Adam Smith
Resources tend to flow to those who value them the most
Example: I will pay you to acquire the car if you currently own it
We don't need to resort to law for mutually-agreeable transactions (like the car)
What's more interesting are incompatible uses of our own property that give rise to conflict
Here, we do need the law to define the rights...but that's not the end of the story
A.C. Pigou
1877-1959
Each party only considering own MPC and MPB
Injurer harms−−−−→ Injured
Examples:
Tax/restrain injurer (A) until his MPC = MSC
Ronald H. Coase
(1910-2013)
Economics Nobel 1991
Harm is actually bilateral, not unilateral
Requires two associating parties to have a dispute
Settling the dispute will impose a cost on some party
Origin of the problem is unclear property rights!
Coase, Ronald H, 1960, "The Problem of Social Cost," Journal of Law and Economics 3:1-44
Ronald H. Coase
(1910-2013)
Economics Nobel 1991
“The traditional approach has tended to obscure the nature of the choice that has to be made. The question is commonly thought of as one in which A inflicts harm on B and what has to be decided is: how should we restrain A? But this is wrong. We are dealing with a problem of a reciprocal nature. To avoid the harm to B would inflict harm on A. The real question that has to be decided is: should A be allowed to harm B or should B be allowed to harm A?” (p.2).
Coase, Ronald H, 1960, "The Problem of Social Cost," Journal of Law and Economics 3:1-44
Ronald H. Coase
(1910-2013)
Economics Nobel 1991
Harm is often bilateral, not unilateral
Takes two parties to have a dispute
A ⟺ B
Origin of the problem is rights are not clear (undefined or unenforced)!
Who has right/responsibility over activity creating the external harm?
Coase, Ronald H, 1960, "The Problem of Social Cost," Journal of Law and Economics 3:1-44
"[Imagine] the case of a confectioner the noise and vibrations from whose machinery disturbed a doctor in his work. To avoid harming the doctor would inflict harm on the confectioner. The problem posed by this case was essentially whether it was worth while, as a result of restricting the methods of production which could be used by the confectioner, to secure more doctoring at the cost of a reduced supply of confectionery products," (p.2).
Coase, Ronald H, 1960, “The Problem of Social Cost” Journal of Law and Economics 3: 1-44
Sturges v Bridgman 11 Ch. D. 852 (1879)
A.C. Pigou
1877-1959
Confectioner is injuring the doctor, the victim and not internalizing the external cost of his machinery
Harm: A→B
Tax offender (A) until his MPC = MSC
Does the Doctor have the right to a quiet work environment?
Does the Confectioner have the right to use own equipment as noisily as he wants?
Note there was no problem until the Doctor expanded his waiting room!
Coase, Ronald H, 1960, “The Problem of Social Cost” Journal of Law and Economics 3: 1-44
Sturges v Bridgman 11 Ch. D. 852 (1879)
Ronald H. Coase
(1910-2013)
Economics Nobel 1991
“The doctor's work would not have been disturbed if the confectioner had not worked his machinery; but the machinery would have disturbed no one if the doctor had not set up his consulting room in that particular place...” (p.13).
Court must must imposing a cost on either the defendant or plaintiff
Real issue is the social balance of efficiency
At what rate is society willing to give up confections for medical services, and vice versa?
Again, it doesn't matter for efficiency to whom the property right is awarded, so long as parties can bargain
If Doctor wins: confectioner can pay doctor to make noise, or buy soundproofing
If Confectioner wins: doctor can pay confectioner to slow/quiet production, or buy soundproofing
Sturges v Bridgman 11 Ch. D. 852 (1879)
Its really George "Stigler's Coase Theorem"
Simplifying assumptions of zero transactions costs
In real world of transactions costs, the assignment of property rights matters!
Property rights and resources are sticky!
Means some allocations are more efficient than others!
Coase: forget "Blackboard economics" and go study the real world of institutions
Launches "Law & Economics" field
How should property rights be assigned to minimize the total cost of externalities and to maximize efficiency?
Most externalities in U.S. mediated through common law legal system
Courts assess how much harm was caused
Individuals causing harm to others must pay:
Externalities persist if property rights are not clear or are not enforced
Even in law there is the distinction between “pecuniary” vs. real externalities
Example: I set fire to your house.
Physical damages: the value of the house destroyed
Pure economic loss: your lost house raises/lowers the value of all houses in the neighborhood
Ronald H. Coase
(1910-2013)
Economics Nobel 1991
Coase provides lots of examples from nuisance cases in common law:
In each case, regardless of who is held liable (or found to have the property right), parties can negotiate to undertake whatever remedy is cheapest to fix (or endure), leading to efficient outcome
Ronald H. Coase
(1910-2013)
Economics Nobel 1991
“Judges have to decide on legal liability but this should not confuse economists about the nature of the economic problem involved. In the case of the cattle and the crops, it is true that there would be no crop damage without the cattle. It is equally true that there would be no crop damage without the crops. The doctor’s work would not have been disturbed if the confectioner had not worked his machinery; but the machinery would have disturbed no one if the doctor had not set up his consulting room in that particular place...” (p.13).
Coase, Ronald H, 1960, “The Problem of Social Cost” Journal of Law and Economics 3: 1-44
Ronald H. Coase
(1910-2013)
Economics Nobel 1991
“If we are to discuss the problem in terms of causation, both parties cause the damage. If we are to attain an optimum allocation of resources, it is therefore desirable that both parties should take the harmful effects into account when deciding on their course of action. It is one of the beauties of a smoothly operating pricing system that...the fall in the value of production due to the harmful effect would be a cost for both parties,” (p.13).
Coase, Ronald H, 1960, “The Problem of Social Cost” Journal of Law and Economics 3: 1-44
Ronald H. Coase
(1910-2013)
Economics Nobel 1991
If transaction costs are low, with well-defined and tradeable property rights, parties can bargain voluntarily to reach the efficient outcome.
Requires:
The initial allocation of property rights does not matter, we will always get the efficient outcome
First Welfare Theorem: competitive markets in equilibrium maximize efficiency
We said this is not true if there are externalities (or other types of market failure), a “missing market”
But defining tradeable property rights and letting parties negotiate is like introducing the “missing market”!
Return to Pierson v. Post — both the majority & dissent implied the ruling mattered for efficiency
Doesn't Coase make the case ruling irrelevant?
Return to Pierson v. Post — both the majority & dissent implied the ruling mattered for efficiency
Doesn't Coase make the case ruling irrelevant?
But it does matter because of transaction costs!
Recall the Coase Theorem is about when transaction costs are low
It also implies the corollary: when transaction costs are high, voluntary bargaining will not reach the efficient outcome!
Ronald H. Coase
(1910-2013)
Economics Nobel 1991
“If market transactions were costless, all that matters (questions of equity apart) is that the rights of the various parties should be well-defined and the results of legal actions easy to forecast.
“But...the situation is quite different when market transactions are so costly as to make it difficult to change the arrangement of rights established by the law.”
“In such cases, the courts directly influence economic activity.”
“Even when it is possible to change the legal delimitation of rights through market transactions, it is obviously desirable to reduce the need for such transactions and thus reduce the employment of resources in carrying them out.”
Coase, Ronald H, 1960, “The Problem of Social Cost” Journal of Law and Economics 3: 1-44
Ronald H. Coase
(1910-2013)
Economics Nobel 1991
“However, I tend to regard the Coase theorem as a stepping stone on the way to an analysis of an economy with positive transaction costs. The significance to me of the Coase theorem is that it undermines the Pigovian system. Since standard economic theory assumes transaction costs to be zero, the Coase theorem demonstrates that the Pigovian solutions are unnecessary in these circumstances. Of course, it does not imply, when transaction costs are positive, that government actions (such as government operation, regulation, or taxation, including subsidies) could not produce a better result than relying on negotiations between individuals in the market. Whether this would be so could be discovered not by studying imaginary governments but what real governments actually do. My conclusion: let us study the world of positive transaction costs,” (p.717).
Coase, Ronald H, 1992, “The Institutional Structure of Production,” American Economic Review 82(4): 713-719
Ronald H. Coase
(1910-2013)
Economics Nobel 1991
“[W]hat are traded on the market are not, as is often supposed by economists, physical entities, but the rights to perform certain actions, and the rights which individuals possess are established by the legal system.” (p.717).
“Because of [transaction costs], the rights which individuals possess, with their duties and privileges, will be, to a large extent, what the law determines. As a result, the legal system will have a profound effect on the working of the economic system and may in certain respects be said to control it. It is obviously desirable that these rights should be as- signed to those who can use them most productively and with incentives that lead them to do so and that, to discover (and maintain) such a distribution of rights, the costs of their transference should be low...” (pp.717-718)
Demand: marginal social benefit (MSB)
Supply: marginal social cost (MSC)
Equilibrium: MSB=MSC
Keyboard shortcuts
↑, ←, Pg Up, k | Go to previous slide |
↓, →, Pg Dn, Space, j | Go to next slide |
Home | Go to first slide |
End | Go to last slide |
Number + Return | Go to specific slide |
b / m / f | Toggle blackout / mirrored / fullscreen mode |
c | Clone slideshow |
p | Toggle presenter mode |
t | Restart the presentation timer |
?, h | Toggle this help |
o | Tile View: Overview of Slides |
Esc | Back to slideshow |
Demand: marginal social benefit (MSB)
Supply: marginal social cost (MSC)
Equilibrium: MSB=MSC
Principle of “payment in accordance with product”
Price system (when markets work well) properly aligns incentives on the margin
Changes that affect others are mitigated through price system
Called pecuniary externalities
The real problem is that it is external to the price system!
People base decisions off of their preferences and opportunity costs of resources for society (captured in prices)
Prices properly negotiate the opportunity costs and provide information to people
But without price, decisions do not internalize those effects!
A.C. Pigou
1877-1959
1920, The Economics of Welfare
Defines (real) externality as divergence between private and social cost/benefit on the margin
People should pay average externality of their actions
Problem with externality is that there is a missing price!
Marginal Private Cost to producer is less than Marginal Social Cost to society
Market Equilibrium (B) too much q at too low p compared to Social Optimum (A)
Marginal Private Cost to producer is less than Marginal Social Cost to society
Market Equilibrium (B) too much q at too low p compared to Social Optimum (A)
Marginal Private Cost to producer is less than Marginal Social Cost to society
Market Equilibrium (B) too much q at too low p compared to Social Optimum (A)
Overproduction due to external cost
A deadweight loss from overproduction
A.C. Pigou
1877-1959
Set a specific tax t=MSC−MPC
Eliminates the DWL
Internalizes the externality into the price system
Producers (and consumers) now consider the true cost to society
"Sitting is banned in the following places: "in St. Mark’s Square and in Piazzetta dei Leoncini, beneath the arcades and on the steps of the Procuratie Nuove, the Napoleonic Wing, the Sansovino Library, beneath the arcades of the Ducal Palace, in the impressive entranceway to St. Mark’s Square otherwise known as Piazzetta San Marco and its jetty." ($200)
"I. A carbon tax offers the most cost-effective lever to reduce carbon emissions at the scale and speed that is necessary. By correcting a well-known market failure, a carbon tax will send a powerful price signal that harnesses the invisible hand of the marketplace to steer economic actors towards a low-carbon future."
Signed by 27 Economics Nobel Laureates, 4 former Federal Reserve chairs, among many other famous economists
"II. A carbon tax should increase every year until emissions reductions goals are met and be revenue neutral to avoid debates over the size of government. A consistently rising carbon price will encourage technological innovation and large-scale infrastructure development. It will also accelerate the diffusion of carbon-efficient goods and services."
Signed by 27 Economics Nobel Laureates, 4 former Federal Reserve chairs, among many other famous economists
"III. A sufficiently robust and gradually rising carbon tax will replace the need for various carbon regulations that are less efficient. Substituting a price signal for cumbersome regulations will promote economic growth and provide the regulatory certainty companies need for long-term investment in clean-energy alternatives."
Signed by 27 Economics Nobel Laureates, 4 former Federal Reserve chairs, among many other famous economists
In 1802, Lodowick Post organized a fox hunt in Southampton, NY
Jesse Pierson appears “out of nowhere,” kills, and claims the fox for his own
Post sued Pierson to get the fox back
Legal question: When do you own an animal?
NY Supreme Court ruled for Pierson (who killed fox)
“If the first seeing, starting, or pursuing such animals...should afford the basis of actions against others for intercepting and killing them, it would prove a fertile source of quarrels and litigation”
“However uncourteous or unkind the conduct of Pierson towards Post, in this instance, may have been, yet his act was productive of no injury or damage for which a legal remedy can be applied. We are of opinion the judgment below was erroneous, and ought to be reversed.”
“[A] fox is a "wild and noxious beast." Both parties have regarded him, as the law of nations does a pirate, "hostem humani generis,"...His depredations on farmers and on barn yards, have not been forgotten; and to put him to death wherever found, is allowed to be meritorious, and of public benefit. Hence it follows, that our decision should have in view the greatest possible encouragement to the destruction of an animal, so cunning and ruthless in his career.”
“But who would keep a pack of hounds; or what gentleman, at the sound of the horn, and at peep of day, would mount his steed, and for hours together...pursue the windings of this wily quadruped, if, just as night came on, and his stratagems and strength were nearly exhausted, a saucy intruder, who had not shared in the honours or labours of the chase, were permitted to come in at the death, and bear away in triumph the object of pursuit?”
If Pierson gets the fox
If Post gets the fox
Tradeoff between simplicity and good incentives
My neighbor likes tall trees
You want to have a party
I own a small plant located on a river
Example: There is a car which you value at $3,000, and I value at $4,000.
Example: There is a car which you value at $3,000, and I value at $4,000.
It is efficient for me to end up with the car.
Suppose I start out with the car
Example: There is a car which you value at $3,000, and I value at $4,000.
It is efficient for me to end up with the car.
Suppose I start out with the car
Suppose instead, you own the car
Example: There is a car which you value at $3,000, and I value at $4,000.
It is efficient for me to end up with the car.
Suppose I start out with the car
Suppose instead, you own the car
It does not matter who is initially assigned a property right, our bargaining will reach the efficient result!
If transaction costs are low, with well-defined and tradeable property rights, parties can bargain voluntarily to reach the efficient outcome.
Coase: there is nothing new or radical here, if you understand Adam Smith
Resources tend to flow to those who value them the most
Example: I will pay you to acquire the car if you currently own it
We don't need to resort to law for mutually-agreeable transactions (like the car)
What's more interesting are incompatible uses of our own property that give rise to conflict
Here, we do need the law to define the rights...but that's not the end of the story
A.C. Pigou
1877-1959
Each party only considering own MPC and MPB
Injurer harms−−−−→ Injured
Examples:
Tax/restrain injurer (A) until his MPC = MSC
Ronald H. Coase
(1910-2013)
Economics Nobel 1991
Harm is actually bilateral, not unilateral
Requires two associating parties to have a dispute
Settling the dispute will impose a cost on some party
Origin of the problem is unclear property rights!
Coase, Ronald H, 1960, "The Problem of Social Cost," Journal of Law and Economics 3:1-44
Ronald H. Coase
(1910-2013)
Economics Nobel 1991
“The traditional approach has tended to obscure the nature of the choice that has to be made. The question is commonly thought of as one in which A inflicts harm on B and what has to be decided is: how should we restrain A? But this is wrong. We are dealing with a problem of a reciprocal nature. To avoid the harm to B would inflict harm on A. The real question that has to be decided is: should A be allowed to harm B or should B be allowed to harm A?” (p.2).
Coase, Ronald H, 1960, "The Problem of Social Cost," Journal of Law and Economics 3:1-44
Ronald H. Coase
(1910-2013)
Economics Nobel 1991
Harm is often bilateral, not unilateral
Takes two parties to have a dispute
A ⟺ B
Origin of the problem is rights are not clear (undefined or unenforced)!
Who has right/responsibility over activity creating the external harm?
Coase, Ronald H, 1960, "The Problem of Social Cost," Journal of Law and Economics 3:1-44
"[Imagine] the case of a confectioner the noise and vibrations from whose machinery disturbed a doctor in his work. To avoid harming the doctor would inflict harm on the confectioner. The problem posed by this case was essentially whether it was worth while, as a result of restricting the methods of production which could be used by the confectioner, to secure more doctoring at the cost of a reduced supply of confectionery products," (p.2).
Coase, Ronald H, 1960, “The Problem of Social Cost” Journal of Law and Economics 3: 1-44
Sturges v Bridgman 11 Ch. D. 852 (1879)
A.C. Pigou
1877-1959
Confectioner is injuring the doctor, the victim and not internalizing the external cost of his machinery
Harm: A→B
Tax offender (A) until his MPC = MSC
Does the Doctor have the right to a quiet work environment?
Does the Confectioner have the right to use own equipment as noisily as he wants?
Note there was no problem until the Doctor expanded his waiting room!
Coase, Ronald H, 1960, “The Problem of Social Cost” Journal of Law and Economics 3: 1-44
Sturges v Bridgman 11 Ch. D. 852 (1879)
Ronald H. Coase
(1910-2013)
Economics Nobel 1991
“The doctor's work would not have been disturbed if the confectioner had not worked his machinery; but the machinery would have disturbed no one if the doctor had not set up his consulting room in that particular place...” (p.13).
Court must must imposing a cost on either the defendant or plaintiff
Real issue is the social balance of efficiency
At what rate is society willing to give up confections for medical services, and vice versa?
Again, it doesn't matter for efficiency to whom the property right is awarded, so long as parties can bargain
If Doctor wins: confectioner can pay doctor to make noise, or buy soundproofing
If Confectioner wins: doctor can pay confectioner to slow/quiet production, or buy soundproofing
Sturges v Bridgman 11 Ch. D. 852 (1879)
Its really George "Stigler's Coase Theorem"
Simplifying assumptions of zero transactions costs
In real world of transactions costs, the assignment of property rights matters!
Property rights and resources are sticky!
Means some allocations are more efficient than others!
Coase: forget "Blackboard economics" and go study the real world of institutions
Launches "Law & Economics" field
How should property rights be assigned to minimize the total cost of externalities and to maximize efficiency?
Most externalities in U.S. mediated through common law legal system
Courts assess how much harm was caused
Individuals causing harm to others must pay:
Externalities persist if property rights are not clear or are not enforced
Even in law there is the distinction between “pecuniary” vs. real externalities
Example: I set fire to your house.
Physical damages: the value of the house destroyed
Pure economic loss: your lost house raises/lowers the value of all houses in the neighborhood
Ronald H. Coase
(1910-2013)
Economics Nobel 1991
Coase provides lots of examples from nuisance cases in common law:
In each case, regardless of who is held liable (or found to have the property right), parties can negotiate to undertake whatever remedy is cheapest to fix (or endure), leading to efficient outcome
Ronald H. Coase
(1910-2013)
Economics Nobel 1991
“Judges have to decide on legal liability but this should not confuse economists about the nature of the economic problem involved. In the case of the cattle and the crops, it is true that there would be no crop damage without the cattle. It is equally true that there would be no crop damage without the crops. The doctor’s work would not have been disturbed if the confectioner had not worked his machinery; but the machinery would have disturbed no one if the doctor had not set up his consulting room in that particular place...” (p.13).
Coase, Ronald H, 1960, “The Problem of Social Cost” Journal of Law and Economics 3: 1-44
Ronald H. Coase
(1910-2013)
Economics Nobel 1991
“If we are to discuss the problem in terms of causation, both parties cause the damage. If we are to attain an optimum allocation of resources, it is therefore desirable that both parties should take the harmful effects into account when deciding on their course of action. It is one of the beauties of a smoothly operating pricing system that...the fall in the value of production due to the harmful effect would be a cost for both parties,” (p.13).
Coase, Ronald H, 1960, “The Problem of Social Cost” Journal of Law and Economics 3: 1-44
Ronald H. Coase
(1910-2013)
Economics Nobel 1991
If transaction costs are low, with well-defined and tradeable property rights, parties can bargain voluntarily to reach the efficient outcome.
Requires:
The initial allocation of property rights does not matter, we will always get the efficient outcome
First Welfare Theorem: competitive markets in equilibrium maximize efficiency
We said this is not true if there are externalities (or other types of market failure), a “missing market”
But defining tradeable property rights and letting parties negotiate is like introducing the “missing market”!
Return to Pierson v. Post — both the majority & dissent implied the ruling mattered for efficiency
Doesn't Coase make the case ruling irrelevant?
Return to Pierson v. Post — both the majority & dissent implied the ruling mattered for efficiency
Doesn't Coase make the case ruling irrelevant?
But it does matter because of transaction costs!
Recall the Coase Theorem is about when transaction costs are low
It also implies the corollary: when transaction costs are high, voluntary bargaining will not reach the efficient outcome!
Ronald H. Coase
(1910-2013)
Economics Nobel 1991
“If market transactions were costless, all that matters (questions of equity apart) is that the rights of the various parties should be well-defined and the results of legal actions easy to forecast.
“But...the situation is quite different when market transactions are so costly as to make it difficult to change the arrangement of rights established by the law.”
“In such cases, the courts directly influence economic activity.”
“Even when it is possible to change the legal delimitation of rights through market transactions, it is obviously desirable to reduce the need for such transactions and thus reduce the employment of resources in carrying them out.”
Coase, Ronald H, 1960, “The Problem of Social Cost” Journal of Law and Economics 3: 1-44
Ronald H. Coase
(1910-2013)
Economics Nobel 1991
“However, I tend to regard the Coase theorem as a stepping stone on the way to an analysis of an economy with positive transaction costs. The significance to me of the Coase theorem is that it undermines the Pigovian system. Since standard economic theory assumes transaction costs to be zero, the Coase theorem demonstrates that the Pigovian solutions are unnecessary in these circumstances. Of course, it does not imply, when transaction costs are positive, that government actions (such as government operation, regulation, or taxation, including subsidies) could not produce a better result than relying on negotiations between individuals in the market. Whether this would be so could be discovered not by studying imaginary governments but what real governments actually do. My conclusion: let us study the world of positive transaction costs,” (p.717).
Coase, Ronald H, 1992, “The Institutional Structure of Production,” American Economic Review 82(4): 713-719
Ronald H. Coase
(1910-2013)
Economics Nobel 1991
“[W]hat are traded on the market are not, as is often supposed by economists, physical entities, but the rights to perform certain actions, and the rights which individuals possess are established by the legal system.” (p.717).
“Because of [transaction costs], the rights which individuals possess, with their duties and privileges, will be, to a large extent, what the law determines. As a result, the legal system will have a profound effect on the working of the economic system and may in certain respects be said to control it. It is obviously desirable that these rights should be as- signed to those who can use them most productively and with incentives that lead them to do so and that, to discover (and maintain) such a distribution of rights, the costs of their transference should be low...” (pp.717-718)