Paul A. Samuelson
1915-2009
Economics Nobel 1970
“Collective consumption goods [are those where] all enjoy in common in the sense that each individual's consumption of such a good leads to no subtractions from any other individual's consumption of that good...” (p.387).
Samuelson, Paul A, 1954, “A Pure Theory of Public Expenditures,” Review of Economics and Statistics 36(4): 387-89
Paul A. Samuelson
1915-2009
Economics Nobel 1970
“[N]o decentralized pricing system can serve to determine optimally these levels of collective consumption. Other kinds of “voting” or “signalling” would have to be tried. But...it is in the selfish interest of each person to give false signals, to pretend to have less interest in a given collective consumption activity than he really has, etc.” (pp.388—389, emphasis in original).
Samuelson, Paul A, 1954, “A Pure Theory of Public Expenditures,” Review of Economics and Statistics 36(4): 387-89
Public Good: a good that is non-rival and non-excludable
Rivalry: one use of a resource removes it from other uses
Excludability: ability or right to prevent others from using it (ownership)
Individual bears a private cost to contribute, but only gets a small fraction of the (dispersed) benefit of a good
If individuals can gain access to the good (nonexcludable) without paying, may lead to...
Free riding: individuals consume the good without paying for it
No incentive for people to contribute and pay for the good
If enough people obtain the benefits without incurring the costs...
Not profitable for private market actors to supply it
Adam Smith
1723-1790
“The third and last duty of the sovereign or commonwealth is that of erecting and maintaining those public institutions and those public works, which, though they may be in the highest degree advantageous to a great society, are, however, of such a nature that the profit could never repay the expence to any individual or small number of individuals, and which it therefore cannot be expected that any individual or small number of individuals should erect or maintain. The performance of this duty requires, too, very different degrees of expence in the different periods of society,” (Book VI, Ch. 9).
Smith, Adam, 1776, An Enquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations
Safner, 2021, “‘Public Good’ or ‘Good for the Public?’ Political Entrepreneurship and the Public Funding of Scientific Research,” Journal of Private Enterprise 36(1): 17-44
Collective action problem: situation where an individual's interest and a group's interest may conflict
Benefits (or costs) of outcome are nonrival and flow to all members of the group
Decisions & costs need to be incurred by individuals
Individual preferences need to aggregate into a single decision/outcome
Groups may share a common interest
But composed of individuals with their own preferences
Additionally, transaction costs/ bargaining to get a group to agree on decision
Mancur Olson
1932-1998
“It is often taken for granted, at least where economic objectives are involved, that groups of individuals with common interests usually attempt to further those common interests. Groups of individuals with common interests are expected to act on behalf of their common interests much as single individuals are often expected to act on behalf of their personal interests...The view that groups act to serve their interests presumably is based upon the assumption that the individuals in groups act out of self-interest...But it is not in fact true that the idea that groups will act in their self-interest follows logically from the premise of rational and self-interested behavior. It does not follow, because...rational self-interested individuals will not act to achieve their common or group interests,” (pp.1-2).
Olson, Mancur, 1962, The Logic of Collective Action
Mancur Olson
1932-1998
“[T]he larger the number of members in the group, the greater the organization costs, and thus the higher the hurdle that must be jumped before any of the collective good at all can be obtained,” (p.48).
“[I]n general, social pressure and social incentive operate only in groups of smaller size, in the groups so small that members can have face-to-face contact with one another,” (p. 62).
Olson, Mancur, 1962, The Logic of Collective Action
Mancur Olson
1932-1998
“[O]nce the smaller member has the amount of the collective good he gets free from the larger member, he has more than he would have purchased himself, and has no incentive to obtain any of the collective good at his own expense’ (p. 35).
Olson, Mancur, 1962, The Logic of Collective Action
Groups often need “selective incentives” to reward contribution and to punish free riding in groups
Positive and negative incentives
Groups provide immaterial, “social/spiritual goods”, to individuals
To be a good member, you must contribute to the group and not just be a drain on its resources
Groups often do some combination of the following to overcome the free rider problem:
Iannaconne, 1992, “Sacrifice and Stigma: Reducing Free-riding in Cults, Communes, and Other Collectives,” Journal of Political Economy 100(2):271-291
James M. Buchanan
1919—2013
Economics Nobel 1986
“No general theory has been developed which covers the whole spectrum of ownership-consumption possibilities, ranging from the purely private or individualized activity on the one hand to purely public or collectivized activity on the other. One of the missing links here is ‘a theory of clubs’, a theory of co-operative membership, a theory that will include as a variable to be determined the extension of ownership-consumption rights over differing numbers of persons,” (p.1).
Buchanan, James M, 1965, “An Economic Theory of Clubs,” Economica 32(125): 1-14
James M. Buchanan
1919—2013
Economics Nobel 1986
“Everyday experience reveals that there exists some most preferred or ‘optimal’ membership for almost any activity in which we engage, and that this membership varies in some relation to economic factors. European hotels have more communally shared bathrooms than their American counterparts. Middle and low income communities organize swimming-bathing facilities; high income communities are observed to enjoy privately owned swimming pools,” (p.1).
Buchanan, James M, 1965, “An Economic Theory of Clubs,” Economica 32(125): 1-14
James M. Buchanan
1919—2013
Economics Nobel 1986
“In this paper I shall develop a general theory of clubs, or consumption ownership-membership arrangements. This construction allows us to move one step forward in closing the awesome Samuelson gap between the purely private and the purely public good. For the former, the optimal sharing arrangement, the preferred club membership, is clearly one person (or one family unit), whereas the optimal sharing group for the purely public good, as defined in the polar sense, includes an infinitely large number of members,” (pp.1-2).
Buchanan, James M, 1965, “An Economic Theory of Clubs,” Economica 32(125): 1-14
Nonrivalrous (but potential excludable) goods with high fixed costs relative to variable costs, i.e. economies of scale with more provision (more members), greater spread of financial cost
Club goods are both excludable and potentially congestible (become more rival)
Provision (of capacity): optimal amount of capacity provided where sum of MB to members from reducing congestion costs = MC of capacity
Utilization (of capacity): charge optimal fee where MB of member from consumption = MC of congestion imposed on other members
Membership: new members added until MB of membership (lower per person cost for members) = MC additional congestion costs from greater size of membership
(High) fixed up-front membership fee
(Low) per-unit use fees
Alexis de Tocqueville
1805-1859
“Americans of all ages, all conditions, and all dispositions, constantly form associations. They have not only commercial and manufacturing companies, in which all take part, but associations of a thousand other kinds – religious, moral, serious, futile, extensive, or restricted, enormous or diminutive. The Americans make associations to give entertainments, to found establishments for education, to build inns, to construct churches, to diffuse books, to send missionaries to the antipodes; and in this manner they found hospitals, prisons, and schools. If it be proposed to advance some truth, or to foster some feeling by the encouragement of a great example, they form a society,” (Book II, Ch. V)
de Tocqueville, Alexis, 1840, Democracy in America
Alexis de Tocqueville
1805-1859
“In democratic countries the science of association is the mother of science; the progress of all the rest depends upon the progress it has made. Amongst the laws which rule human societies there is one which seems to be more precise and clear than all others. If men are to remain civilized, or to become so, the art of associating together must grow and improve in the same ratio in which the equality of conditions is increased,” (Book II, Ch. V)
de Tocqueville, Alexis, 1840, Democracy in America
Elinor Ostrom
1933—2012
Economics Nobel 2009
Variety of solutions are possible for managing a commons efficiently
So long as they set up good rules that solve the free rider problem, remove the incentive to overuse resource, negative externality on others
Elinor Ostrom
1933—2012
Economics Nobel 2009
“The classic assumptions about rational individuals facing a dichotomy of organizational forms and of goods hide the potentially productive efforts of individuals and groups to organize and solve social dilemmas such as the overharvesting of common-pool resources and the underprovision of local public goods. the classic models have been used to view those who are involved in a Prisoner’s dilemma game or other social dilemmas as always trapped in the situation without capabilities to change the structure themselves. this analytical step was a retrogressive step in the theories used to analyze the human condition,” (p.416)
Ostrom, Elinor, 2009, “Beyond Markets and States: Polycentric Governance of Complex Economic Systems,” Nobel Prize Lecture
Elinor Ostrom
1933—2012
Economics Nobel 2009
“Garrett hardin’s (1968) portrayal of the users of a common-pool resource – a pasture open to all – being trapped in an inexorable tragedy of overuse and destruction has been widely accepted since it was consistent with the prediction of no cooperation in a Prisoner’s dilemma or other social dilemma games,” (p.417).
Ostrom, Elinor, 2009, “Beyond Markets and States: Polycentric Governance of Complex Economic Systems,” Nobel Prize Lecture
Elinor Ostrom
1933—2012
Economics Nobel 2009
“Actors who have specific property rights to a resource also face more fundamental rules that affect the structure of the action situations they are in. In our meta-analysis, we found an incredible array of specific rules used in different settings..As we attempted to find a consistent way of coding and analyzing this rich diversity of specific rules described by case authors, we turned again to the IAD framework. Since we had identified seven working parts of a game or action situation itself, it seemed reasonable to think of seven broad types of rules operating as external variables affecting the individual working parts of action situations,” (p.420).
Ostrom, Elinor, 2009, “Beyond Markets and States: Polycentric Governance of Complex Economic Systems,” Nobel Prize Lecture
Elinor Ostrom
1933—2012
Economics Nobel 2009
“The seven types of rules are:
- Boundary rules that specify how actors were to be chosen to enter or leave these positions;
- Position rules that specify a set of positions and how many actors hold each one;
- choice rules that specify which actions are assigned to an actor in a position;
- information rules that specify channels of communication among actors and what information must, may, or must not be shared;
- scope rules that specify the outcomes that could be affected;
- aggregation rules (such as majority or unanimity rules) that specify how the decisions of actors at a node were to be mapped to intermediate or final outcomes; and
- Payoff rules that specify how benefits and costs were to be distributed to actors in positions,” (p.420).
Ostrom, Elinor, 2009, “Beyond Markets and States: Polycentric Governance of Complex Economic Systems,” Nobel Prize Lecture
Safner, Ryan, 2016, “Institutional Entrepreneurship, Wikipedia, and the Opportunity of the Commons,” Journal of Institutional Economics 12(4): 743-771
1790—1891 U.S. did not recognize copyrights to foreign authors
U.S. publishing industry largely pirated famous British authors
Safner, Ryan, 2021, “Honor Among Thieves: How 19th Century American Pirate Publishers Simulated Copyright Protection”
Keyboard shortcuts
↑, ←, Pg Up, k | Go to previous slide |
↓, →, Pg Dn, Space, j | Go to next slide |
Home | Go to first slide |
End | Go to last slide |
Number + Return | Go to specific slide |
b / m / f | Toggle blackout / mirrored / fullscreen mode |
c | Clone slideshow |
p | Toggle presenter mode |
t | Restart the presentation timer |
?, h | Toggle this help |
o | Tile View: Overview of Slides |
Esc | Back to slideshow |
Paul A. Samuelson
1915-2009
Economics Nobel 1970
“Collective consumption goods [are those where] all enjoy in common in the sense that each individual's consumption of such a good leads to no subtractions from any other individual's consumption of that good...” (p.387).
Samuelson, Paul A, 1954, “A Pure Theory of Public Expenditures,” Review of Economics and Statistics 36(4): 387-89
Paul A. Samuelson
1915-2009
Economics Nobel 1970
“[N]o decentralized pricing system can serve to determine optimally these levels of collective consumption. Other kinds of “voting” or “signalling” would have to be tried. But...it is in the selfish interest of each person to give false signals, to pretend to have less interest in a given collective consumption activity than he really has, etc.” (pp.388—389, emphasis in original).
Samuelson, Paul A, 1954, “A Pure Theory of Public Expenditures,” Review of Economics and Statistics 36(4): 387-89
Public Good: a good that is non-rival and non-excludable
Rivalry: one use of a resource removes it from other uses
Excludability: ability or right to prevent others from using it (ownership)
Individual bears a private cost to contribute, but only gets a small fraction of the (dispersed) benefit of a good
If individuals can gain access to the good (nonexcludable) without paying, may lead to...
Free riding: individuals consume the good without paying for it
No incentive for people to contribute and pay for the good
If enough people obtain the benefits without incurring the costs...
Not profitable for private market actors to supply it
Adam Smith
1723-1790
“The third and last duty of the sovereign or commonwealth is that of erecting and maintaining those public institutions and those public works, which, though they may be in the highest degree advantageous to a great society, are, however, of such a nature that the profit could never repay the expence to any individual or small number of individuals, and which it therefore cannot be expected that any individual or small number of individuals should erect or maintain. The performance of this duty requires, too, very different degrees of expence in the different periods of society,” (Book VI, Ch. 9).
Smith, Adam, 1776, An Enquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations
Safner, 2021, “‘Public Good’ or ‘Good for the Public?’ Political Entrepreneurship and the Public Funding of Scientific Research,” Journal of Private Enterprise 36(1): 17-44
Collective action problem: situation where an individual's interest and a group's interest may conflict
Benefits (or costs) of outcome are nonrival and flow to all members of the group
Decisions & costs need to be incurred by individuals
Individual preferences need to aggregate into a single decision/outcome
Groups may share a common interest
But composed of individuals with their own preferences
Additionally, transaction costs/ bargaining to get a group to agree on decision
Mancur Olson
1932-1998
“It is often taken for granted, at least where economic objectives are involved, that groups of individuals with common interests usually attempt to further those common interests. Groups of individuals with common interests are expected to act on behalf of their common interests much as single individuals are often expected to act on behalf of their personal interests...The view that groups act to serve their interests presumably is based upon the assumption that the individuals in groups act out of self-interest...But it is not in fact true that the idea that groups will act in their self-interest follows logically from the premise of rational and self-interested behavior. It does not follow, because...rational self-interested individuals will not act to achieve their common or group interests,” (pp.1-2).
Olson, Mancur, 1962, The Logic of Collective Action
Mancur Olson
1932-1998
“[T]he larger the number of members in the group, the greater the organization costs, and thus the higher the hurdle that must be jumped before any of the collective good at all can be obtained,” (p.48).
“[I]n general, social pressure and social incentive operate only in groups of smaller size, in the groups so small that members can have face-to-face contact with one another,” (p. 62).
Olson, Mancur, 1962, The Logic of Collective Action
Mancur Olson
1932-1998
“[O]nce the smaller member has the amount of the collective good he gets free from the larger member, he has more than he would have purchased himself, and has no incentive to obtain any of the collective good at his own expense’ (p. 35).
Olson, Mancur, 1962, The Logic of Collective Action
Groups often need “selective incentives” to reward contribution and to punish free riding in groups
Positive and negative incentives
Groups provide immaterial, “social/spiritual goods”, to individuals
To be a good member, you must contribute to the group and not just be a drain on its resources
Groups often do some combination of the following to overcome the free rider problem:
Iannaconne, 1992, “Sacrifice and Stigma: Reducing Free-riding in Cults, Communes, and Other Collectives,” Journal of Political Economy 100(2):271-291
James M. Buchanan
1919—2013
Economics Nobel 1986
“No general theory has been developed which covers the whole spectrum of ownership-consumption possibilities, ranging from the purely private or individualized activity on the one hand to purely public or collectivized activity on the other. One of the missing links here is ‘a theory of clubs’, a theory of co-operative membership, a theory that will include as a variable to be determined the extension of ownership-consumption rights over differing numbers of persons,” (p.1).
Buchanan, James M, 1965, “An Economic Theory of Clubs,” Economica 32(125): 1-14
James M. Buchanan
1919—2013
Economics Nobel 1986
“Everyday experience reveals that there exists some most preferred or ‘optimal’ membership for almost any activity in which we engage, and that this membership varies in some relation to economic factors. European hotels have more communally shared bathrooms than their American counterparts. Middle and low income communities organize swimming-bathing facilities; high income communities are observed to enjoy privately owned swimming pools,” (p.1).
Buchanan, James M, 1965, “An Economic Theory of Clubs,” Economica 32(125): 1-14
James M. Buchanan
1919—2013
Economics Nobel 1986
“In this paper I shall develop a general theory of clubs, or consumption ownership-membership arrangements. This construction allows us to move one step forward in closing the awesome Samuelson gap between the purely private and the purely public good. For the former, the optimal sharing arrangement, the preferred club membership, is clearly one person (or one family unit), whereas the optimal sharing group for the purely public good, as defined in the polar sense, includes an infinitely large number of members,” (pp.1-2).
Buchanan, James M, 1965, “An Economic Theory of Clubs,” Economica 32(125): 1-14
Nonrivalrous (but potential excludable) goods with high fixed costs relative to variable costs, i.e. economies of scale with more provision (more members), greater spread of financial cost
Club goods are both excludable and potentially congestible (become more rival)
Provision (of capacity): optimal amount of capacity provided where sum of MB to members from reducing congestion costs = MC of capacity
Utilization (of capacity): charge optimal fee where MB of member from consumption = MC of congestion imposed on other members
Membership: new members added until MB of membership (lower per person cost for members) = MC additional congestion costs from greater size of membership
(High) fixed up-front membership fee
(Low) per-unit use fees
Alexis de Tocqueville
1805-1859
“Americans of all ages, all conditions, and all dispositions, constantly form associations. They have not only commercial and manufacturing companies, in which all take part, but associations of a thousand other kinds – religious, moral, serious, futile, extensive, or restricted, enormous or diminutive. The Americans make associations to give entertainments, to found establishments for education, to build inns, to construct churches, to diffuse books, to send missionaries to the antipodes; and in this manner they found hospitals, prisons, and schools. If it be proposed to advance some truth, or to foster some feeling by the encouragement of a great example, they form a society,” (Book II, Ch. V)
de Tocqueville, Alexis, 1840, Democracy in America
Alexis de Tocqueville
1805-1859
“In democratic countries the science of association is the mother of science; the progress of all the rest depends upon the progress it has made. Amongst the laws which rule human societies there is one which seems to be more precise and clear than all others. If men are to remain civilized, or to become so, the art of associating together must grow and improve in the same ratio in which the equality of conditions is increased,” (Book II, Ch. V)
de Tocqueville, Alexis, 1840, Democracy in America
Elinor Ostrom
1933—2012
Economics Nobel 2009
Variety of solutions are possible for managing a commons efficiently
So long as they set up good rules that solve the free rider problem, remove the incentive to overuse resource, negative externality on others
Elinor Ostrom
1933—2012
Economics Nobel 2009
“The classic assumptions about rational individuals facing a dichotomy of organizational forms and of goods hide the potentially productive efforts of individuals and groups to organize and solve social dilemmas such as the overharvesting of common-pool resources and the underprovision of local public goods. the classic models have been used to view those who are involved in a Prisoner’s dilemma game or other social dilemmas as always trapped in the situation without capabilities to change the structure themselves. this analytical step was a retrogressive step in the theories used to analyze the human condition,” (p.416)
Ostrom, Elinor, 2009, “Beyond Markets and States: Polycentric Governance of Complex Economic Systems,” Nobel Prize Lecture
Elinor Ostrom
1933—2012
Economics Nobel 2009
“Garrett hardin’s (1968) portrayal of the users of a common-pool resource – a pasture open to all – being trapped in an inexorable tragedy of overuse and destruction has been widely accepted since it was consistent with the prediction of no cooperation in a Prisoner’s dilemma or other social dilemma games,” (p.417).
Ostrom, Elinor, 2009, “Beyond Markets and States: Polycentric Governance of Complex Economic Systems,” Nobel Prize Lecture
Elinor Ostrom
1933—2012
Economics Nobel 2009
“Actors who have specific property rights to a resource also face more fundamental rules that affect the structure of the action situations they are in. In our meta-analysis, we found an incredible array of specific rules used in different settings..As we attempted to find a consistent way of coding and analyzing this rich diversity of specific rules described by case authors, we turned again to the IAD framework. Since we had identified seven working parts of a game or action situation itself, it seemed reasonable to think of seven broad types of rules operating as external variables affecting the individual working parts of action situations,” (p.420).
Ostrom, Elinor, 2009, “Beyond Markets and States: Polycentric Governance of Complex Economic Systems,” Nobel Prize Lecture
Elinor Ostrom
1933—2012
Economics Nobel 2009
“The seven types of rules are:
- Boundary rules that specify how actors were to be chosen to enter or leave these positions;
- Position rules that specify a set of positions and how many actors hold each one;
- choice rules that specify which actions are assigned to an actor in a position;
- information rules that specify channels of communication among actors and what information must, may, or must not be shared;
- scope rules that specify the outcomes that could be affected;
- aggregation rules (such as majority or unanimity rules) that specify how the decisions of actors at a node were to be mapped to intermediate or final outcomes; and
- Payoff rules that specify how benefits and costs were to be distributed to actors in positions,” (p.420).
Ostrom, Elinor, 2009, “Beyond Markets and States: Polycentric Governance of Complex Economic Systems,” Nobel Prize Lecture
Safner, Ryan, 2016, “Institutional Entrepreneurship, Wikipedia, and the Opportunity of the Commons,” Journal of Institutional Economics 12(4): 743-771
1790—1891 U.S. did not recognize copyrights to foreign authors
U.S. publishing industry largely pirated famous British authors
Safner, Ryan, 2021, “Honor Among Thieves: How 19th Century American Pirate Publishers Simulated Copyright Protection”