Voters express preferences through elections
Special interest groups provide additional information and advocacy for lawmaking
Politicians create laws reflecting voter and interest group preferences
Bureaucrats implement laws according to goals set by politicians
Judges interpret laws to settle individual disputes
Special interest groups: any group of individuals that value a common cause
SIGs as economic agents:
Choose: < candidate/policy to support >
In order to maximize: < utility >
Subject to: < budget >
Enormous variety of interest groups: business industries, environmental groups, religious groups, taxpayers, government agencies, etc.
Pluralism: a wide distribution of many groups with different viewpoints on any given issue (or priorities across issues)
Democracy as a grand bargain between varying interest groups on issues
Role of politicians as leaders to mediate these groups
But power and influence is not evenly distributed across interest groups
Olsonian logic: Smaller and more homogenous groups face lower collective action costs of organizing than larger and more heterogeneous groups
Smaller groups to whom benefit (cost) of a policy is more concentrated can outmobilize larger groups where benefit (cost) is more dispersed
"In fiscal year (FY) 2013, Americans consumed 12 million tons of refined sugar, with the average price for raw sugar 6 cents per pound higher than the average world price. That means, based on 24 billion pounds of refined sugar use at a 6-cents-per-pound U.S. premium, Americans paid an unnecessary $1.4 billion extra for sugar. That is equivalent to more than $310,000 per sugar farm in the United States"
Source: Heritage Foundation
"Washington, D.C., doesn't have many farms, or farmers. Yet thousands of residents in and around the nation's capital receive millions of dollars every year in federal farm subsidies...lawyers, lobbyists and at least one psychologist collected nearly $342,000 in taxpayer farm subsidies between 2008 and 2011...[also] Gerald Cassidy, the founder of one of Washington's most powerful lobbying firms, Cassidy & Associates; Charlie Stenholm, a former congressman; and Chuck Grassley, a Republican senator from Iowa; [and former] Secretary of Agriculture Tom Vilsack..."
And yet, each individual pays maybe $1-2 a year in higher prices for sugar
Difficult to mobilize voters to petition to end the sugar subsidy to save $1
Sugar producers stand to lose a billion dollars
Sugar PACs that contribute thousands to key lawmakers
Imagine a “market” for regulation (or laws, policy, etc.) — who are the participants?
Demanders: voters, interest groups, bureaucracy (?)
Suppliers: politicians, bureaucracy, interest groups (?)
What determines the regulation we have?
Tarko, Vlad and Ryan Safner, 2022, “The Variety of Regulatory Regimes”
Think of an economic rent as a "prize," the payment a person receives for a good above its opportunity cost
Creating rents creates competition for the rents, causing people to invest resources in rent-seeking
The cost of the rent is not just the rent itself, but the resources invested in rent-seeking!
These interventions create economic rents for their beneficiaries by reducing competition
This is a transfer of wealth from consumers/taxpayers to politically-favored groups
The promise of earning a rent breeds competition over the rents (rent-seeking)
In 1950, 1 in 20 jobs required a license. Today it's 1 in 4. Source: Obama White House (2015): Occupational Licensing: A Framework for Policymakers
"'It is illegal in the state of Utah to do any form of extensions without a valid cosmetology license," the e-mail read. "Please delete your ad, or you will be reported.'
To get a license, Jestina would have to spend more than a year in cosmetology school. Tuition would cost $16,000 dollars or more."
Source: NPR Planet Money
George Stigler
1911-1991
Economics Nobel 1982
All groups desire to use the State to protect their interests (create rents)
Direct subsidies boost profits but can induce entry into the industry
Control of entry reduces competition and increases rents to incumbents
Olsonian problem: More organized industries fare better in controlling politics than less organized
Stigler, George J, (1971), "The Theory of Economic Regulation," Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 3:3-21
George Stigler
1911-1991
Economics Nobel 1982
"[A]s a rule, regulation is acquired by the industry and is designed and operated primarily for its benefits," (p.3).
"[E]very industry or occupation that has enough political power to utilize the state will seek to control entry. In addition, the regulatory policy will ofeten be so fashioned as to retard the rate of growth of new firms," (p.5).
Stigler, George J, (1971), "The Theory of Economic Regulation," Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 3:3-21
Regulatory capture: a regulatory body is "captured" by the very industry it is tasked with regulating
Industry members use agency to further their own interests
One major source of capture is the "revolving door" between the public and private sector
Legislators & regulators retire from politics to become highly paid consultants and lobbyists for the industry they had previously "regulated"
A large industrial economy requires complex regulation on very technical issues
Experts in the industry tend to know the most about these fields
Key resource is information, not necessarily money or influence
“Professional lobbyists are among the most experienced, knowledgeable, and strategic actors one can find in the everyday practice of politics. Nonetheless, their behavioral patterns often appear anomalous when viewed in the light of existing theories...We model lobbying not as exchange (vote buying) or persuasion (informative signaling) but as a form of legislative subsidy — a matching grant of policy information, political intelligence, and legislative labor to the enterprises of strategically selected legislators. The proximate political objective of this strategy is not to change legislators' minds but to assist natural allies in achieving their own, coincident objectives,” (p. 69).
“In sum, lobbyists freely but selectively provide labor, policy information, and political intelligence to likeminded but resource-constrained legislators. Legislators, in turn, should seek policy-relevant services from likeminded lobbyists. The effect is to expand legislators' effort at making progress toward a policy objective that lobbyists and legislators share,” (p.75).
Hall, Richard and Alan Deardorff, 2006, “Lobbying as Legislative Subsidy,” American Political Science Review 100(1): 69-84
Lobbying is an essential part of a modern democracy
Democracy as one big extended discussion
The socially-optimal amount of lobbying is not 0!
Olson: collective action/free rider problem is larger for larger groups
Rational ignorance of voters
Caplan: voters are rationally irrational about policy
Tullock-Stigler: it's often in the interests of industries to seek rents
Olson: collective action/free rider problem is larger for larger groups
Rational ignorance of voters
Caplan: voters are rationally irrational about policy
Tullock-Stigler: it's often in the interests of industries to seek rents
Yandle: rent-seeking can be masked by publicly noble intentions
Bruce Yandle
1933-
"What do industry and labor want from the regulators? They want protection from competition, from technological change, and from losses that threaten profits and jobs. A carefully constructed regulation can accomplish all kinds of anticompetitive goals of this sort, while giving the citizenry the impression that the only goal is to serve the public interest," (p.13).
Yandle, Bruce, 1983, "Bootleggers and Baptists: The Education of a Regulatory Economist," Regulation
Regulations are often supported by two categories of groups:
"Baptists": group that supports the ostensible public-interest purpose of the regulation
"Bootleggers": group that supports the regulation because it generates rents for them
Bootleggers often adopt the language of Baptists
Voters express preferences through elections
Special interest groups provide additional information and advocacy for lawmaking
Politicians create laws reflecting voter and interest group preferences
Bureaucrats implement laws according to goals set by politicians
Judges interpret laws to settle individual disputes
Keyboard shortcuts
↑, ←, Pg Up, k | Go to previous slide |
↓, →, Pg Dn, Space, j | Go to next slide |
Home | Go to first slide |
End | Go to last slide |
Number + Return | Go to specific slide |
b / m / f | Toggle blackout / mirrored / fullscreen mode |
c | Clone slideshow |
p | Toggle presenter mode |
t | Restart the presentation timer |
?, h | Toggle this help |
o | Tile View: Overview of Slides |
Esc | Back to slideshow |
Voters express preferences through elections
Special interest groups provide additional information and advocacy for lawmaking
Politicians create laws reflecting voter and interest group preferences
Bureaucrats implement laws according to goals set by politicians
Judges interpret laws to settle individual disputes
Special interest groups: any group of individuals that value a common cause
SIGs as economic agents:
Choose: < candidate/policy to support >
In order to maximize: < utility >
Subject to: < budget >
Enormous variety of interest groups: business industries, environmental groups, religious groups, taxpayers, government agencies, etc.
Pluralism: a wide distribution of many groups with different viewpoints on any given issue (or priorities across issues)
Democracy as a grand bargain between varying interest groups on issues
Role of politicians as leaders to mediate these groups
But power and influence is not evenly distributed across interest groups
Olsonian logic: Smaller and more homogenous groups face lower collective action costs of organizing than larger and more heterogeneous groups
Smaller groups to whom benefit (cost) of a policy is more concentrated can outmobilize larger groups where benefit (cost) is more dispersed
"In fiscal year (FY) 2013, Americans consumed 12 million tons of refined sugar, with the average price for raw sugar 6 cents per pound higher than the average world price. That means, based on 24 billion pounds of refined sugar use at a 6-cents-per-pound U.S. premium, Americans paid an unnecessary $1.4 billion extra for sugar. That is equivalent to more than $310,000 per sugar farm in the United States"
Source: Heritage Foundation
"Washington, D.C., doesn't have many farms, or farmers. Yet thousands of residents in and around the nation's capital receive millions of dollars every year in federal farm subsidies...lawyers, lobbyists and at least one psychologist collected nearly $342,000 in taxpayer farm subsidies between 2008 and 2011...[also] Gerald Cassidy, the founder of one of Washington's most powerful lobbying firms, Cassidy & Associates; Charlie Stenholm, a former congressman; and Chuck Grassley, a Republican senator from Iowa; [and former] Secretary of Agriculture Tom Vilsack..."
And yet, each individual pays maybe $1-2 a year in higher prices for sugar
Difficult to mobilize voters to petition to end the sugar subsidy to save $1
Sugar producers stand to lose a billion dollars
Sugar PACs that contribute thousands to key lawmakers
Imagine a “market” for regulation (or laws, policy, etc.) — who are the participants?
Demanders: voters, interest groups, bureaucracy (?)
Suppliers: politicians, bureaucracy, interest groups (?)
What determines the regulation we have?
Tarko, Vlad and Ryan Safner, 2022, “The Variety of Regulatory Regimes”
Think of an economic rent as a "prize," the payment a person receives for a good above its opportunity cost
Creating rents creates competition for the rents, causing people to invest resources in rent-seeking
The cost of the rent is not just the rent itself, but the resources invested in rent-seeking!
These interventions create economic rents for their beneficiaries by reducing competition
This is a transfer of wealth from consumers/taxpayers to politically-favored groups
The promise of earning a rent breeds competition over the rents (rent-seeking)
In 1950, 1 in 20 jobs required a license. Today it's 1 in 4. Source: Obama White House (2015): Occupational Licensing: A Framework for Policymakers
"'It is illegal in the state of Utah to do any form of extensions without a valid cosmetology license," the e-mail read. "Please delete your ad, or you will be reported.'
To get a license, Jestina would have to spend more than a year in cosmetology school. Tuition would cost $16,000 dollars or more."
Source: NPR Planet Money
George Stigler
1911-1991
Economics Nobel 1982
All groups desire to use the State to protect their interests (create rents)
Direct subsidies boost profits but can induce entry into the industry
Control of entry reduces competition and increases rents to incumbents
Olsonian problem: More organized industries fare better in controlling politics than less organized
Stigler, George J, (1971), "The Theory of Economic Regulation," Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 3:3-21
George Stigler
1911-1991
Economics Nobel 1982
"[A]s a rule, regulation is acquired by the industry and is designed and operated primarily for its benefits," (p.3).
"[E]very industry or occupation that has enough political power to utilize the state will seek to control entry. In addition, the regulatory policy will ofeten be so fashioned as to retard the rate of growth of new firms," (p.5).
Stigler, George J, (1971), "The Theory of Economic Regulation," Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 3:3-21
Regulatory capture: a regulatory body is "captured" by the very industry it is tasked with regulating
Industry members use agency to further their own interests
One major source of capture is the "revolving door" between the public and private sector
Legislators & regulators retire from politics to become highly paid consultants and lobbyists for the industry they had previously "regulated"
A large industrial economy requires complex regulation on very technical issues
Experts in the industry tend to know the most about these fields
Key resource is information, not necessarily money or influence
“Professional lobbyists are among the most experienced, knowledgeable, and strategic actors one can find in the everyday practice of politics. Nonetheless, their behavioral patterns often appear anomalous when viewed in the light of existing theories...We model lobbying not as exchange (vote buying) or persuasion (informative signaling) but as a form of legislative subsidy — a matching grant of policy information, political intelligence, and legislative labor to the enterprises of strategically selected legislators. The proximate political objective of this strategy is not to change legislators' minds but to assist natural allies in achieving their own, coincident objectives,” (p. 69).
“In sum, lobbyists freely but selectively provide labor, policy information, and political intelligence to likeminded but resource-constrained legislators. Legislators, in turn, should seek policy-relevant services from likeminded lobbyists. The effect is to expand legislators' effort at making progress toward a policy objective that lobbyists and legislators share,” (p.75).
Hall, Richard and Alan Deardorff, 2006, “Lobbying as Legislative Subsidy,” American Political Science Review 100(1): 69-84
Lobbying is an essential part of a modern democracy
Democracy as one big extended discussion
The socially-optimal amount of lobbying is not 0!
Olson: collective action/free rider problem is larger for larger groups
Rational ignorance of voters
Caplan: voters are rationally irrational about policy
Tullock-Stigler: it's often in the interests of industries to seek rents
Olson: collective action/free rider problem is larger for larger groups
Rational ignorance of voters
Caplan: voters are rationally irrational about policy
Tullock-Stigler: it's often in the interests of industries to seek rents
Yandle: rent-seeking can be masked by publicly noble intentions
Bruce Yandle
1933-
"What do industry and labor want from the regulators? They want protection from competition, from technological change, and from losses that threaten profits and jobs. A carefully constructed regulation can accomplish all kinds of anticompetitive goals of this sort, while giving the citizenry the impression that the only goal is to serve the public interest," (p.13).
Yandle, Bruce, 1983, "Bootleggers and Baptists: The Education of a Regulatory Economist," Regulation
Regulations are often supported by two categories of groups:
"Baptists": group that supports the ostensible public-interest purpose of the regulation
"Bootleggers": group that supports the regulation because it generates rents for them
Bootleggers often adopt the language of Baptists